In this week’s module, we review the
concept of the rise and fall of great powers and the establishment of global or
regional hegemons. Of all of the
articles we explored for this module, Mark Beeson’s piece titled “Hegemonic
Transition in East Asia? The dynamics of Chinese and American power” was by far
the most interesting. This article
causes us to ask the question: how do we determine what constitutes a “hegemon”
and does military might really matter as much as it used to? This week’s readings really caused me to
question much of what I thought I knew about the structure of international politics and the role of coercion and
reason (and by extension, interests and ideas).
I will briefly explore the previously held assumptions, which were
deconstructed by our readings, below.
Military might, which is an extension of
(and product of) economic power, is what ultimately will determine the world
hegemon. Or at least, this is what I
thought before diving into the readings.
The nation with the biggest stick and the best ability to project its
power will always possess the ability to influence politics to their advantage,
either in their region or globally (depending on the size of their
military). The U.S. is a clear example
of this. With the world’s strongest
military by far, the U.S. has managed to influence affairs in nearly every
corner of the globe. Backed by a strong
economy, the U.S. military possess the ability to project its power the world
over, which makes it even easier to influence global affairs.
Beeson pointed out that the role of
military might may well be diminishing, however.
On page 96, he states “American military might is less valuable than it
once was, and this has given added significance to China’s growing economic
power”. He speaks of this “intersection
of material power and ideas” (99) and claims “it is not obvious that this military
strength is as decisive as it once was, or that the ability of other countries like
China to challenge American dominance should be judged exclusively or even
primarily by their ability to counter conventional military might” (100). He also mentions the idea that there may be
other “increasingly relevant and utilizable forms of structural power”, which
he suggests are softer forms of power (ibid).
This gets back to the first two modules we worked through in this
course, and causes us to again consider whether it is coercion or
reason—interests or ideas—which matter most in determining not only state
behavior, but state relationships and how they are stratified against one
another.
Beeson further illustrated this point by
discussing ASEAN +3 agreement, which he argues is a result of China’s “activist
diplomacy” as it “explicitly excludes
the US and reflects a much more narrowly defined conception of ‘East Asia’, rather
than the all encompassing notion of an ‘Asia-Pacific’ region that has been championed
by the US” (105). By using its soft
power and adopting “soft balancing” techniques, China seems to have burrowed
its way into the institutional framework of the region and leveraged institutions
(in upper left box of the 2x2 fashion…) to advance its agenda. Whether or not this will eventually lead to
its surpassing the current hegemon, the U.S., remains to be seen.
With all of that having been said, it appears as though reason and ideas may well matter much more than traditionlists might contend. That China today is working to undermine (and perhaps even use to its advantage) the very institutions the U.S. set to protect its hegemonic power, suggests that soft power may matter more at the end of the day. While the article did cause me to rethink my assumptions about the importance of military and economic might in determining a hegemon, ultimately, I remain confident that both matter a great deal. Perhaps military might and economic power must be coupled with some greater, over-arching ideal to really matter, but its necessity I think is very difficult to refute.
With all of that having been said, it appears as though reason and ideas may well matter much more than traditionlists might contend. That China today is working to undermine (and perhaps even use to its advantage) the very institutions the U.S. set to protect its hegemonic power, suggests that soft power may matter more at the end of the day. While the article did cause me to rethink my assumptions about the importance of military and economic might in determining a hegemon, ultimately, I remain confident that both matter a great deal. Perhaps military might and economic power must be coupled with some greater, over-arching ideal to really matter, but its necessity I think is very difficult to refute.
In addition to these challeneges, this week’s readings left me with three other major
questions, which I hope to discuss in class.
First, what really matters in
determining hegemons (or even “great” powers)?
Are they determined solely based on the realist models that value
material, interest-based power or do soft forms of power like ideas and
influence, carry more weight? Secondly,
how do the concepts of hegemony and agency interrelate? One might assume that hegemons have far more
agency than their great power subordinates, but is this really the case? The example mentioned above concerning the
U.S. inability to effectively manipulate the ASEAN agreement (and to
“structure” the region in ‘Asia-Pacific’ terms) illustrates how even the most
powerful nations on Earth can have limited agency. How are those limits determined? Thirdly, going back to the Kenneth Waltz
reading about structure and this idea of balancing, how are hegemons allowed to
come into being? If Waltz was correct
and states are inclined to balance in Risk-like fashion to prevent any one
state from becoming too powerful, how is it that hegemons are allowed to exist
at all?
I look forward to exploring these topics and more in this week’s live session.
Mark Beeson, “Hegemonic transition in East
Asia? The Dynamics of Chinese and American Power,” Review of International
Studies 35:1 (2009).
No comments:
Post a Comment